When Professor of Political Science Mark Blyth was growing up in
Dundee, Scotland, in the 1970s and 1980s, unemployment rates in the
United Kingdom were the highest they’d been since World War II. “When I
left school, nobody said, ‘What are you doing for a job?’ They just
said, ‘Where are you signing on?’” he recalls. “In other words, ‘Where
are you getting your unemployment?’ There was almost a sort of
expectation that you might do a lot of things in your life, but work
might not be one of them.”
But even in those bad times, Blyth recalls, the state was there with
its safety net. “Capitalism with airbags,” he calls it. “The type of
capitalism I am a fan of.”
“Because of the British welfare state, threadbare though it is in
comparison to its more affluent European cousins, I was never hungry,”
he says. “My grandmother’s pension plus free school meals took care of
that. I never lacked shelter because of social housing. The schools I
attended were free and actually acted as ladders of mobility for those
randomly given the skills in the genetic lottery of life to climb them.”
In April, Blyth, who studies international political economy, published Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea,
his critique of the economic approach that governments in both the
United States and Europe have applied in recent years. “It’s crap,” he
says of the approach. “It doesn’t work. But it’s dangerous crap.” It
dismantles those airbags for the poor, he says, and provides them only
for the rich—an economic intervention that only exacerbates the
conditions it is meant to address.
“What made it possible for me to become the man I am today,” Blyth
writes in Austerity, “is the very thing now blamed for creating the
crisis itself: the state, more specifically, the runaway, bloated,
paternalist, out-of-control welfare state.”
Had austerity been the predominant approach in the United Kingdom
during his childhood, Blyth argues, he would most likely not be a
professor today. “I am,” he writes in Austerity, “as extreme an example
of intragenerational social mobility as you can find anywhere.”
You may have heard the buzzwords on the news: Growth-friendly fiscal
consolidation. Expansionary fiscal contraction. They’re synonyms for
austerity, the idea that governments can best reverse economic
slowdowns by slashing spending and raising taxes. “The resulting growth
would help them to pay back debts,” explains John Cochrane, a
University of Chicago economist who supports this approach, “and market
recognition of that fact would let them borrow in the meantime and
avoid a debt crisis.”
Austerity, Blyth says, is a twenty-first-century example of something
he’s been studying and writing about his entire career: the power of
ideas. Something need not be true to have a very real impact on
people’s lives, he argues. “So long as something about the economy is
believed by a large enough group of people, then because they believe
it, it becomes true,” he wrote in his 2002 book, Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century.
The idea that cutting government spending and slashing public services
will lead to economic prosperity by promoting investor confidence may
be, as Blyth asserts, ludicrous on its face, yet the fact that enough
people believe it has led to austerity’s widespread implementation and
set the stage for what Blyth says will be “a generation of misery”
throughout Europe: millions of unemployed and angry young people stuck
in downwardly spiraling economies.
Blyth speaks with a Scottish brogue, an easy confidence, and a potty
mouth. His quick-witted intelligence and his sense of humor are
obvious, though his anger and passion are less so: the more worked up
he becomes about a subject, the more deadpan his presentation. And when
he discusses austerity—the way it stacks the deck and contributes to an
unfair and unequal society—his face goes blank and he begins to talk
with the rat-a-tat delivery of an auctioneer.
Blyth came of age during a time of great economic and social upheaval
in the United Kingdom. Margaret Thatcher became prime minister when he
was twelve. “What Mrs. Thatcher did was to take a rather complacent and
comfortable set of social institutions and arrangements,” he says,
“stick dynamite under them, detonate them, and not really give a damn
about the casualties.”
Aside from her more obvious endeavors, such as beating down unions, he
says, Thatcher tried to address Britain’s persistent unemployment by
changing the nation’s culture of work, taxation, and ownership. “She
changed people’s conception of themselves,” Blyth says. “She gave them
the right to buy their houses that were officially state-owned. Next
thing, you get this ridiculously subsidized mortgage. The next thing,
you get a mortgage tax deduction. The next thing, you’re buying a new
front door to signify to everyone that you’re different from them. And
what you’re doing is, you’re creating new political identities. So the
whole project of Thatcherism was creating interests where they didn’t
exist before.”
While in high school, Blyth dated a young woman who was studying
politics and economics at the local university. Reading her course
books was a revelation; he saw his own life reflected in their pages.
Suddenly his community wasn’t buffeted just by economic forces beyond
anyone’s control: The books gave them context, backstory. They offered
explanation, analysis, insight.
He played bass in rock bands—some good, some not so good—and, inspired
by his girlfriend’s books, enrolled in college. “And because we had
this thing called the welfare state, where you could do this,” he says,
“I went to college part-time for free, and I got the qualifications
necessary to go on to university. And that’s what I did.”
Blyth’s father argued that Labour would spend money on creating jobs,
which would make prices go up and leave no money for schools and
hospitals, which would force the government to borrow, which—given the
inflation they had created—would be expensive, and leave “less money
for everyone else. This means we will have to pay more on loans and
things, so people will have less money to spend. The less people spend,
the more the economy slows down, so there are fewer people working. If
the Tories get in again, they’ll cut taxes, people will spend more, and
there will be more jobs.”
Blyth was “bemused and impressed,” and he challenged his dad: “So why
does the money you spend that comes from a tax cut create jobs while
the money spent by a Labour government creates inflation?”
After a brief pause, his father answered, “Because it does. Governments shouldn’t do that kind of thing.”
Later, as a graduate student studying economics, Blyth thought about
his dad when he was taught that we all act in our own self-interest.
One of the basic tenets of economics, he learned, is that we make the
choices that we determine will most benefit us materially—make us
richer and more successful, help us get ahead. And when all of us
individually pursue our own fortunes, the market is inevitably
optimized: many self-interested actors together add up to the perfect
economy.
“That’s what economics assumes: the notion of rational expectations,”
he says. Central banking models assume that each of us is a rational
agent “running around optimizing choices given certain bits of
information. We actually have in our head the structure of the economy
written as an equation. We actually know the value of all the
coefficients governing it, and we constantly update, and we optimize as
we go through life,” he continues. “And it seems painfully obvious to
me that about 40 percent of the country can’t do long division. Once
you basically say, ‘That’s dubious, that’s problematic,’ you’ve then
got to say, ‘Well, how do people fill in the gaps?’
“What they do is they tell themselves stories.”
They tell themselves stories about the value of hard work and
self-reliance, say, about the appropriate role of government or the
laziness of the poor, and they act and vote accordingly, whether or not
their own economic self-interest is served.
“Ideas matter,” Blyth wrote in Great Transformations,
“because they can actually alter people’s conception of their own
self-interest.” Much like the British voters who suddenly discovered
that it was in their self-interest to own their own home, what begins
as a story, an emotion, soon has widespread and very concrete
implications.
To Blyth nothing illustrates this better than “Growth-friendly fiscal
consolidation.” Though it sounds like the perfect solution to all
our financial problems, the notion that indebted countries can, during
an economic downturn, cut their way to economic prosperity is, Blyth
says: “A fairy story.”
Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea is a scathing and
detailed takedown of this fairy story from all sides. Blyth critiques
austerity’s intellectual history (paltry, he says), its practical
history (in his case study of fifteen countries he discovered that it
has never, ever worked), and its ethical underpinnings
(“indefensible”—“disgusting,” even).
Five years into the “great recession,” with U.S. unemployment rates continuing to hover at roughly double what they were for the previous twenty years, we’re told that austerity is the “pain after the party”: the price for decades of out-of-control government spending.
But this is a lie, Blyth says. A deliberate bait-and-switch. In
reality, austerity is the price the rest of us must pay for saving the
banks: “The cost of bailing, recapitalizing, and otherwise saving the
global banking system… has ended up on the balance sheets of
governments as they absorb the costs of the bust,” he writes, “which is
why we mistakenly call this a sovereign debt crisis when in fact it is
a transmuted and well-camouflaged banking crisis.”
The people who generated great personal wealth in the process of
creating this mess—bankers and financiers who invented products like
mortgage-backed securities and credit-default swaps —are now “actively
eschewing any responsibility for that problem by blaming the state for
their mistakes,” Blyth writes. Cutting government spending inevitably
means cutting social programs that, by and large, the wealthy don’t
use: public education, public transportation, food assistance, and
health care. Blyth argues that austerity is the rich demanding that the
rest of us pay for their mistakes: “socialism for the rich and
capitalism for the poor. I’m all in favor of everyone tightening their
belts the minute we’re all wearing the same pants. But we’re not.”
As someone with a keen sense of what it feels like to depend on these
social programs, Blyth feels personally affronted by proponents of
austerity who slash these programs and then are dishonest about why
they’re doing it.
“State bad, market good” was the standard way of thinking in the years
before the financial crisis. Get the government out of the way and the
market will always right itself. In reality, Blyth says, “there’s no
difference between states and markets. States make markets,” he says.
“They either make them possible, through the promulgation of laws,
weights, measures, courts, all the rest of it, or, more deeply and more
often, they create markets. They create firms. They create credit
markets. They force savings. They create rates of interest. They create
the entire environment in which you can incubate what we now call
capitalism.”
But those in power believed it was true that markets would prosper with
minimal state intervention—a belief that fueled decades of
deregulation, which in turn paved the way for the financial meltdown.
All the ostensibly level-headed talk about getting our financial house
in order, Blyth says, is in fact a cover for the true intentions of
austerity’s proponents: weakening the state, shrinking the government,
and eliminating sovereign debt at all costs.
In Austerity, Blyth locates the origins of this type of
thinking in such early thinkers as Locke, Hume, and Smith: “Saving is a
virtue, spending is a vice,” he writes. “Hence countries that save must
be doing the right thing, while spenders must be storing up trouble.”
This philosophy resonates in a country like the United States, with its
Puritan ancestors and runaway credit-card debt. Trouble is, Blyth says,
it doesn’t make sense. And the sooner we recognize that, the sooner we
can get back on sound financial footing.
We cannot all cut our way to growth at the same time. Blyth frames one
of his major objections to austerity as common sense. “A debt … is
someone’s asset and income stream, not just someone else’s liability,”
Blyth writes. By the same logic, “For someone to benefit from a
reduction in wages, … there must be someone else who is willing to
spend money on what that person produces.” But if everyone takes a wage
cut, everyone has less money to spend:“If we all save at once there is
no consumption to stimulate investment.”
This is true on a macro level, too: “This problem is especially
pernicious under a policy of generalized austerity, because if a
country’s private and public sectors are both paying back debt at the
same time,” Blyth writes, “the only way that country can grow is by
exporting more…to a state that is still spending. But, if everyone is
trying the same strategy of not spending, as is happening in Europe
today, it becomes self-defeating.”
Proponents of austerity point out that countries with high debt-to-GDP
ratios have slow economic growth. This seems like a reasonable
rationale for cutting debt: too much debt appears to hamper growth. But
Blyth and others point out that this mixes up cause and effect:
countries develop high debt-to-GDP ratios because they have slow
growth, not the other way around. This makes intuitive sense: an
economic slowdown leads to lower tax revenues as fewer people are
working and wages decrease; simultaneously, governments must spend more
on such safety net programs as unemployment and food stamps.
Part of Austerity is devoted to case studies in which
countries in modern history have tried to use the approach to promote
growth. “To me, the shocking part was, I went into it with the
understanding that there were positive cases,” Blyth says. He looked
closely at examples like Canada in the 1980s or the United States in
the late 1990s—examples that proponents of austerity often cite as
proof that it works. What he found was that these countries’ economies
were growing already, and with their tax receipts increasing, they used
that increased income, quite sensibly, to pay down debt. “Bravo!” Blyth
says. “But that’s not austerity.”
So what is the alternative?
First and foremost, Blyth says, countries trying to cure recessions by
implementing drastic budget cuts simply need to stop. It’s “Hippocratic
capitalism,” he says: “First, do no harm.” Part of the reason the U.S.
economy has recovered more quickly than Europe’s, he says, is the
stalemate in Congress: “Because the Republicans and Democrats haven’t
been able to do anything, the economy is at least partially recovered.”
Beyond doing nothing, Blyth says, the best way out of a recession is
through more government spending. In other words, you can cure debt
with more debt. “One in three bridges in the United States is falling
down,” he says. “Repairing this at a time when you can borrow at
basically negative real rates is a hugely obvious, great thing to do.
Investing in light rail, smart rail—there are tons of things you can
do, all of which are productivity-enhancing.” The more jobs you create,
he says, the more people will pay taxes. The higher the tax receipts,
the more readily you’re able to pay down debt.
Many proponents of austerity say they are in favor of spending on
things like light rail, and that painting them as cold-hearted budget
slashers is unfair. “Austerity is a word that has been twisted to all
sorts of ridiculous meanings, to the point that it is now one of Lewis
Carroll’s words that mean whatever its speaker wants it to mean,” they
University of Chicago’s John Cochrane, whom Blyth describes in his book
as a “pro-austerity advocate,” wrote me in an e-mail. “Saying you’re
for austerity is now pretty much just a meaningless insult.”
Cochrane continued, “This is not about roads and bridges,
infrastructure, keeping the lights on, or all the other usual red
herrings,” he says. It’s not about cutting all government spending but
rather wasteful government spending, alongside “freeing up
over-regulated markets.” In Europe, Cochrane wrote, “austerity has come
to mean a package focused mostly on raising distorting taxes to
astronomical levels, and particularly on anyone who dares to invest,
run a business, or hire someone, with essentially no reduction in
government spending and no structural reform. Well, duh, that isn’t
going to work, and it has not… I am adamantly not for that, nor ever
was.”
Even Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart, the two Harvard economists
whose paper is often cited as proof that austerity works (the very same
paper whose Excel spreadsheet error garnered a lot of media attention),
were never “big boosters of austerity in the recession,” Rogoff told
me—that was a distortion of their position. He and Reinhart actually
favor fiscal stimulus as part of a package of reforms, he said,
primarily “high-return investments in infrastructure and education.”
This was precisely the rationale behind the Obama administration’s
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. For a brief period,
some of the world’s largest economies seemed to agree that a big burst
of government spending was the best way to reverse the recession. That
is, until a G20 meeting in Toronto during the summer of 2010 at which
the twenty most powerful economies in the world got together to reverse
course. Their oft-cited communiqué called for “growth-friendly fiscal
consolidation.”
Thanks in part to the cultural changes initiated by Mrs. Thatcher, the
working-class Dundee, Scotland, of Blyth’s childhood is no more. “So
for me, cognitively, interpersonally, the place where I grew up no
longer exists,” he says. He has lived outside Scotland so long that
“it’s literally a foreign country.”
Blyth shares this sense with his wife, who grew up in East Germany and fled to the United States and England as soon as the wall came down. “Although Germany is there, she didn’t grow up in Germany. The country she grew up in literally no longer exists,” Blyth reflects.
Both of them are classic American immigrants who have become citizens.
“This really is our home,” Blyth says. Blyth’s critiques of the United
States arise from love and admiration for his adopted home. He wants to
make it better, more prosperous, and a more welcoming place for others.
“I often bring up [my wife] in talks when people are dragging on about
the American state being wasteful and terrible,” Blyth recalls. “I say,
‘Really?’ It’s funny, because my wife’s from East Germany. She thinks
the American state’s pretty awesome. It faced down the Communists. It
put a guy on the moon. If you’re on the East German side of things, the
United States has got a pretty damn good state.”
Blyth tends to agree, though he is frustrated that the state has been
falling short on its responsibility to make sure everyone gets a fair
shot.
“Frankly,” he writes in Austerity, “the world could use a few more welfare kids that become professors. It keeps the rest honest.”
Beth Schwartzapfel is a BAM contributing editor.